This graphic shows relative rate of various surgical procedures in Massachusetts compared to the rest of the United States. Massachusetts has lower than average utilization for most of these procedures. This data is from the Dartmouth Atlas, which is based on Medicare utilization by state. Utilization and cost in the Medicare program is not necessarily equivalent to total utilization and cost for all state residents.
The Massachusetts Paradox
This graphic shows relative rate of various surgical procedures in Massachusetts compared to the rest of the United States. Massachusetts has lower than average utilization for most of these procedures. This data is from the Dartmouth Atlas, which is based on Medicare utilization by state. Utilization and cost in the Medicare program is not necessarily equivalent to total utilization and cost for all state residents.
Maryland Hospitals Sue Poor Patients For Payments Despite Rates That Incorporate Payment for Bad Debt
Maryland has a unique arrangement where the state sets rates for all payers, including Medicare. The rates are set to incorporate costs of unpaid care for each hospital. Essentially, hospitals can wrap the cost of this year's unpaid care into their future bills. Under this program, Maryland hospital bills have grown at a slower rate than the rest of the country, and Medicare payments to Maryland are inflated by as much as $500 million per year.
The Sun reporters created a database of all civil lawsuits filed to collect for hospital bills, a total of 132,000 lawsuits with over $100 million of judgments. The investigating team discovered that there are no standards for when medical bills are written off as free care, and there are wide disparities from hospital to hospital. Furthermore, some hospitals “double dip” by writing off bills as bad debt (and building this into their rates), and then later suing patients for the charges which had previously been written off.
Johns Hopkins acknowledged sending 20% of its patients to collection, and the Maryland Hospital Association expressed pride that the industry sends only ½% of patients to collection. Hospitals routinely charged higher interests rates than allowed by law, and at times sued patients for payments not made by Medicaid, a violation of provider participation rules for that federal-state program. Many hospitals had substantial surpluses attributed to high rates to make up for uncompensated care.
Hospitals are in substantial financial distress across the country - and bad debt rates are likely to increase in coming months. Hospital are obligated to try to collect legitimate debts; otherwise, the costs for those who do pay will go way too high. But suing patients with no resources and charging them credit-card-worthy interest rates is unseemly, and suing even after the bad debt has been factored into future bills seems at least immoral, and probably illegal.
Thanks to John Petito of our Harvard School of Public Health class for pointing this series out to me.
Congressional Budget Office Throws Down the Gauntlet
Health Care in Massachusetts
Primary Care Shortage - Diminishing With Economic Woes
Regional Variations in Medicare Coverage
Health Care is NOT Recession-Proof (an ongoing series)
Massachusetts Quality and Cost Council - MyHealthCareChoices Site Unveiled
Massachusetts’ Health Quality and Cost Council has just unveiled its new public transparency web site, MyHealthCareOptions, which is available at http://hcqcc.hcf.state.ma.us/. The state has taken claims data from the major commercial health plans, and ascertained cost of care by hospital for a limited number of procedures. It has also assembled related quality data, generally from different sources (since it’s hard to determine quality through claims alone). This was a big effort, and the web site allows patients to filter by geography and compare up to 4 hospitals. Where possible, there is notation of level of statistical certainty. (For instance, a low volume hospital might have an apparently high cost, but this would be more likely to be due to chance rather than a real difference).
It’s a good start – but the data available on cost is limited to 1-4 stars (representing top 15% of cost, above average, below average, and bottom 15% of cost. Actual dollar numbers and relative prices, as displayed in a Globe article a few weeks ago, would be more meaningful than percentiles. Some additional information I’d like as a consumer which is not currently displayed includes:
- Patient experience by service, rather than hospital-wide
- Volume for surgical procedures, where more volume often leads to higher proficiency
- Rate of caesarian section by hospital. While there is no “right” rate, some women might prefer to go to a hospital with lower C-section rates.
It’s also impressive how often there is no generally accepted quality data. It’s hard to describe “value” when we only know the cost and don’t have a good way to ascertain the quality of the health care we purchase.
Who will look at this web site? My own experience is that it will be reviewed largely by providers rather than consumer – and that’s just fine. The site might make some hospitals feel pressured to implement some safety processes (like computerized physician order entry) and work harder to improve patient experiences. The site might help pressure some organizations to accept lower rate increases, although it’s also likely to make many single $ institutions push much harder for large rate increases.
Closing "Bad" Hospitals
But the hospital's administration has lobbied hard, and its unions are important ally. A year after the Berger Commission recommended that University Hospital be merged (and shrunk), there has been no progress.
Why is it so hard to close an "underperforming" hospital?
1) Jobs - hospitals are the major employers in many communities
2) Convenience - closing hospitals usually means that someone will have to travel further for care
3) Professionals - Physicians are reluctant to move from one facility to another
4) Patient loyalty - I remember the public outcry in Massachusetts when a number of small community facilities closed.
Does closing underperforming hospitals lower the cost of care?
Not necessarily. While closing a hospital means there is less capital deployed and could decrease supply-induced demand, weaker hospitals slated for closure often have lower rates, and patients move to higher cost facilities. This is not the case with University Hospital in Syracuse, where costs are above the state average. Of course, all costs must be risk adjusted for severity of illness. The data cited in the Times regarding University Hospital IS risk adjusted, although it's always possible to argue the risk adjustment is not adequate.
In Massachusetts, the cardiac surgery program at UMass Memorial was closed in 2005 due to higher than expected risk-adjusted mortality. The program was voluntarily shut just before legally mandated state public reporting of mortality statistics. The leadership at UMass has written honestly about the experience, and ultimately recruited a new team of cardiac surgeons and now has reopened with excellent safety metrics. UMass lost its cardiac surgery training program due to this event. (Harvard link) (Non Harvard link)
Health care demand elasticity in a recession -- many warning signs
I've also talked to a number of senior hospital executives over the last few weeks, and they are reeling from
(1) Slowdown in philanthropy, with some donors not coming through with pledged funds
(2) Increase in accounts receivable, as payers have slowed down payment
(3) Increase in bad debt, as patients lose their insurance
(4) Decrease in revenue, as patients are not coming in for elective procedures, including orthopedic surgery, CT scans and MRI scans. Making this still worse, these elective procedures provide the highest margin for hospitals.
This is one more blow against the notion that health care is "recession-proof."
(Note the WSJ link will work for ~5 days -- after that, use this URL).
Comparative Effectiveness -- Maybe Not a Panacea?
This is especially important, because the Obama health care plan, the Daschle health care plan, and many others include an institute of comparative effectiveness to be sure we spend our health care resources wisely. NICE is usually the model for this.