Primary Care and Specialty Pay Across Countries

Double click on images to enlarge them




The OECD published data last month showing the relative pay of PCPs and specialists across 14 countries.   The US had the highest relative pay for primary care physicians, while the Netherlands had the highest relative pay for specialists (with the US in a close second.)  Most countries had less disparity between the multiplier of PCP pay to average wage and that of specialist to average wage.   Note that this report counts pediatricians and probably many internists as specialists - so it understates the income disparities.  Here is a link to the full report.




The US is not the only country with a lot of new technology (But ours is more expensive!)



One of the students from our class this fall, Elad Sharon, writes from his journey on a public health school trip to India:

 

I have been impressed by the number of MRI's here.  I suspect that there are more MRI's in the Indian state of Kerala than in Canada (similar populations, but vastly different incomes, of course).  It seems that the Indian health system is also enamored of technology, and cost-cutting strategies focus on reducing unnecessary tests and unnecessary care.  Insurance schemes are rudimentary at best, and generally organized by government unions or even, in one case, a cancer hospital.  Definitely, eye-opening.  Labor costs are ridiculously cheap, but the needs are immense.  Non-Resident Indians (NRI's) distort the market generally, and may actually inadvertently fund the technology development.

 

 Many countries have far more MRI scanners than the United States on a population basis.  For instance, Japan has 40 MRIs per million population, and the US has 26.5.  (Canada has only 6.2).  The difference is that MRIs in India (not part of the OECD study) cost 5000-7000 rupees ($102-$140), whereas MRIs cost Massachusetts health plans a median of $700 , and the “list price” is probably twice that. 

Some Indian provinces have high supply of MRIs, but their cost per unit is quite low. The US has a trifecta - the combination of high supply, high utilization, and high prices.  

 

 

 


 

WSJ op-ed assails comparative effectiveness research

The January 20 Wall Street Journal included an op-ed from the American Enterprise Institute decrying the potential for a government-funded comparative effectiveness institute.

In this opinion piece, Scott Gottlieb suggests that such a government-funded comparative effectiveness institute
(1) Will not save money
(2) Will use poor scientific methods
(3) Would do research that would be effectively done by the private sector if only the FDA would allow private companies to publicize their comparative effectiveness findings.

My response:
(1) Here are the CBO comments from December, 2007.

Generating additional information about comparative effectiveness and making corresponding changes in incentives would seem likely to reduce health care spending over time—potentially to a significant degree. The precise impact, however, depends on several factors and is difficult to predict. Given the time necessary to conduct the research, to alter incentives in a manner reflecting the results, and to affect behavior through those changes, any potential for substantial cost savings from new research would probably take a decade or more to materialize. Even so, generating additional information comparing treatments would tend to reduce federal health spending somewhat in the near term—but that effect may not be large enough to offset the full costs of conducting the research over that same time period


(2) There is some thought that we might have to settle for research that wouldn’t merit publication in the New England Journal. Question – isn’t some information even if imperfect better than the current state of utter lack of information?

(3) The CBO points out that private parties just don’t have the right incentives to do good comparative effectiveness research. Pharmaceutical and device makers are not likely to be impartial enough (Here’s an example. This article showing that a medicine was ineffective was published in Annals of Internal Medicine 8 years after the completion of data collection. The publication was delayed until long after fluconazole, the drug in question, lost its patent protection). . On the payer side, there is no single health plan (except perhaps Medicare) representing enough of the market to take on this cost.

Comparative effectiveness research is expensive and takes a long time. The UK's National Institute of Clinical Effectiveness faces serious opposition to its efforts to restrict coverage to more cost-effective therapies. (See my previous post on this issue). Doing good comparative effectiveness research could help allocate precious (and not limitless) resources. This research won't happen without government participation, and probably won't have much impact as long as government payers are prohibited from using this information in coverage decisions. I believe we should fund this research through the Agency for Health Research and Quality, and governmental and nongovernmental payers should be able to use this information when designing coverage.

Thanks to Ben Geisler from our class for sending me a link to this article.